We live now in a time of symbolic money,but it was not always like this. Today money is represented by pieces of paper as non-redeemable official bills whose quantity can be increased without any effort by the monetary authorities of the country.

Until the beginning of the twentieth century the most popular and universal medium of exchange was gold and silver coins. Currency was considered to be as free as any other merchandise. People responding to their own particular needs demanded the coins and also offered them, thus their market value was established daily.

The symbolic money originated from private contracts or promises of payments issued by goldsmiths and later by banks which became common among businessmen. The private contract issued in favour of a particular person to be paid at a particular time became increasingly more abstract until it reached today's non-redeemable note. The private contract became payable to the bearer rather than to a particular person, then it became payable on demand rather than at a particular time.

The next evolutionary jump took place as more governments moved in support of their national bank's notes as national currency. This resulted in more people becoming used to it as a 'substitute' for gold and silver. Then,in periods of emergency, the government could suspend the obligation to redeem the notes, effectively making them the unique money in circulation.

The final stage took place when the governments discovered the potential of the artificial currency to cover their own financial deficit. That was achieved through a special legislation that made their notes 'legal money' and it obliged people to accept them as payment of all official debts. After many decades, the governments eliminated all the merchandise currencies- gold and silver coins - from circulation. Thus the non-redeemable promise of payment of the government became the only available medium of exchange. A purely symbolic and artificial money had been created.

On this issue of money many people have fought before. Paper-money was defended by the usurers and the economists, who maintained that money could be substituted by symbols which were the property of the state. It was attacked by the defenders of freedom who maintained that money was not the monopoly of the state and therefore was a commodity like any other one. Here follow some of the arguments.

The Economists

It was a maxim of Roman Law that the value of money was fixed by Imperial decree. It was expressly forbidden to treat money as a commodity. "However, it shall not be lawful for anyone to buy money, for, as it was created for public use, it is not permissible for it to be a commodity."
(Codex Theodosianus, lib. 9, tit. 23)

Nicholas Barbon deduced the right of the state "to raise money", i.e. to give to the quantity of silver called a shilling the name of a greater quantity, such as crown, and so to pay back shillings to creditors instead of crowns. "Money does wear and grow lighter by often telling over... It is the denomination and currency of the money that men regard in bargaining, and not the quantity of silver... 'Tis the public authority upon the metal that makes it money."
(Barbon, Nicholas, A Discourse on Coining the New Money Lighter. In Answer to Mr. Locke's Considerations etc., London, 1696, p.25, 29, 30)

"That, as far as concerns our domestic exchanges, all the monetary functions which are usually performed by gold and silver coins, may be performed as effectually by a circulation of inconvertible notes having no value but that fictitious and conventional value... that they derive from the law, is a fact which admits, I conceive, of no denial." (Fullarton, John, On the Regulations of Currencies, 2nd edn., London, 1848, p. 21)

"Money is their (the commodities) symbol."
(Forbonnais, François-Véron de, Élémens du commerce, new edn., Leyden, 1776, Vol. 2, p. 143)

"Money is a symbol of a thing and represents it."
(Montesquieu, Charles-Louis de, Esprit des lois (1748), in Oeuvres, London, 1767, Vol. 2, p. 3)

"The fact that the circulation of money itself splits the nominal content of coins away form their real content, dividing their metallic existence from their functional existence, this fact implies the latent possibility of replacing metallic money with tokens made of some other material, i.e., symbols which would perform the function of coins."
(Marx, Carl, Capital (1867), ed. Penguin, London, 1976, Vol. 1, pp. 222-3)

The Freedom Guardians

"Money is not a mere symbol, for it is itself wealth; it does not represent the values, it is their equivalent." (Le Trosne, Guillaume-François, De l'intérêt social par rapport à la valeur, à la circulation, à l'industrie, et au commerce intérieur et exterieur [1777], in Physiocrates, ed. Daire, part 2, Paris, 1846, p. 910)

"Whether one of these two values is money, or whether they are both ordinary commodities, is in itself a matter of complete indifference." (Mercier de la Rivière, Paul Pierre le, L'Ordre naturel et essentiel des sociétés politiques [1767], in Physiocrates, ed. E. Daire, Part 2, Paris, 1846)

"Money is the universal commodity."
(Verri, Pietro, Meditazioni sulla economia politica [1771], in Scrittori Classici italiani di economia politica, Parte moderna, ed. Custodi, Vol. 15, Milan, 1804, p. 16)

"Silver and gold, coined or uncoined, tho' they are used for a measure of all other things, are no less a commodity than wine, oil, tobacco, cloth or stuffs."
(Child, Josiah, A Discourse Concerning Trade, and That in Particular of the East-Indies etc., London, 1689, p. 2)

"Gold and silver have value as metals before they are money."

"The coins which today have a merely ideal denomination are in all nations the oldest; once upon a time they were all real, and because they were real people reckoned with them."
(Galiani, Ferdinando, Della Moneta, p. 72, 153, Vol. 3 of Custodi's collection entitled Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica, Parte moderna, Milan, 1803)

"The false definitions of money may be divided in two main groups: those which make it more, and those which make it less, than a commodity."
(Wilhelm Roscher, Die Grundlagen der Nationalökonomie, 3rd. edn, Stuttgart, 1858, pp. 207)

 

Go to Chapter 6

The Return of the Gold Dinar